Joint Congressional Executive Committee on China
Property Rights Roundtable
February 3, 2003
Written Statement of Patrick A. Randolph, Jr.
Elmer E. Pierson Professor of Real Estate Law
University of Missouri, Kansas City, School of Law
I
am an American academic and lawyer specializing in real estate law, including
leasing, finance, development and title issues.
I have served in the leadership of the American Bar Association Section
on Real Property, Probate and Trust Law for many years and have published eight
books and scores of articles on American real estate issues.
Ten
years ago I was invited to teach Real Estate Law at Peking University, and thus
began an interest in the development of Chinese real estate law that I observed
in its beginning stage at that time.
Since then, I have traveled to China frequently and have invited Chinese
scholars to collaborate with me in America.
I have co-authored a book and a number of articles on Chinese Real
Estate Law and have lectured on real estate topics at most of the major Chinese
law schools. I have established academic
programs for Chinese students in America and for American students in
China. Recently, I have participated in
the Center on Chinese Land Law and Policy at Peking University, which will
develop a central source of information in English and Chinese, regarding developments
in Chinese Real Estate Law, and to provide a resource of American expertise on
real estate matters for Chinese practitioners and policy makers. I will serve as co-Director of the Center.
My
book, Chinese Real Estate Law, published by Kluwer International Law
Publishers, is the only book length treatment of this topic in English written
by someone with background in real estate law practice. I attempt to synthesize the various sources
of Chinese law to suggest the way Chinese law would address problems of concern
to persons involved in market real estate transactions.
I
do not speak or read Chinese, and my expertise is based upon collaboration with
Chinese lawyers and academics who speak English. Although this necessarily is a limitation on
my development of any true expertise, I can say that at the elite Chinese law
schools I have been able to interact with students and academics from every
part of China, have obtained insights that one might not obtain from government
or business organs.
1. Overview of Chinese Real Estate System:
1.1.
Introduction:
Until
1988, there was one simple law of real estate in China - the government owns
everything. Although the government
divided its control of the land resources in China into different compartments
and vested various governmental elements with responsibility and control, there
were no individual rights in land and any arrangements that had been made could
be unmade by government fiat.
In
1988, China amended its Constitution to provide for the recognition of
privately owned transferable rights in land.
Although the Chinese Constitution does not have the same force of law
that the American Constitution does, this change was an important symbolic
step, and presaged an array of changes in governmental statutes and regulations
that implemented a system of private ownership and exchange of real
estate. The developmental process was
slowed by political unrest in China occurring also in 1988, and when I arrived
in 1992, China was just beginning to act on the development opportunities
offered by the legal changes.
Since
1992, there has been real estate activity in China’s cities on a scale perhaps
unequaled in human history. Certainly
the legal system that has been developed since 1988 has been a critical element
in accomplishing this real estate activity, but the physical development has
surged far beyond the legal development.
China
has some law in place, and there certainly is recognition and protection of
ownership. Private bargains can be struck with some degree of assurance that
the law will enforce them. Lenders have
some clarity of right to reach security given for loans. But there is little certainty, on a
nationwide basis, that the rights technically recognized in the Chinese laws
will be fully recognized by those who administer the Chinese legal system,
although there is steady improvement in this area.
Perhaps
more important is the fact that the Chinese real estate system has yet to
undergo the test that will come when the “first bubble bursts” - when China’s
real estate market experiences the inevitable economic correction that must
come as part of the cycle of economic activity.
It is only then that we will know how well the rights and expectations
created by the system will stand up to the pressures of political
expediency. We have had the same “test
of fire” of the legal system in this country a number of times during our
history, and each time we have identified weakness that needed correction.
In
short, the existence of a “rule of law” cannot be proclaimed. It must be experienced. It must be measured
again and again as new pressures arise to test its stability. No social system is immune from such tests,
and no legal system responds to these tests perfectly. Since the system of private rights was first
established, China has yet to experience its first real test.
1.2. Basic Characteristics of the System:
The
basic building block of the U.S. real estate economy is perpetual and
relatively comprehensive ownership. The “fee
simple absolute” is an ownership interest in land that can be transferred and
inherited indefinitely into the future.
It cannot be said to be “absolute ownership” because land rights in
America are subject to rather extensive government regulation. But that which is not regulated or limited by
the rights of other landowners is owned outright. This basic concept permits enormous
flexibility in the American economic system.
Those who hold such rights can divide and redivide these interests in
thousands of ways, and our complex private economy attests to the inventiveness
of American property owners to find the highest and best use of various aspects
of land ownership.
By
contrast, the basic element of ownership of Chinese land is far more
limited. The “granted land use right” is
given for an identified period - 40 to 70 years depending upon the purpose for
the grant. Although, theoretically,
there are some renewal rights, the time for renewal of any such rights is still
well in the future, and the terms of renewal remain uncertain. The right is given by government only for
purposes of implementing a particular use, and permission must be obtained to
change the use. It should be noted,
however, that in most cases these use restrictions are no different than use
restrictions typically imposed in America through zoning and land use
laws. A more important limitation is
that speculation in raw land is restricted through the requirement that the user
commence the required use within two years.
If the property is not developed, it cannot be transferred and in fact
it may be forfeited back to the government.
In
addition, it should be noted that the land use right in China does not carry
with it the extended package of rights to subsurface and above surface
activities that American ownership typically has included. The Chinese government continues to control
all mineral resources and air rights.
Over time, the U.S. has moved to a significant restriction of these
rights in American property as well, however.
The
granted land use right is similar in some ways to the long term ground lease
that is commonly used in America to develop commercial sites. The difference is that the Chinese right is
obtained from, and reverts to, the government, rather than a private owner, and
the consideration for the right is paid “up front,” and is forfeitable if the
property is not developed.
Chinese
granted land use rights are protected from expropriation without compensation.
China
has a reasonably reliable system of registration of land use rights that
permits identification of the owners. In
an important recent development, China has established that there shall be
unrestricted public access to these land records nationwide - an important
development that western investors have been seeking for some time.
Since
the land use right can be transferred, China has developed a system of rules
governing the leasing, mortgaging and sale of these rights. The rights can also be inherited and there
are rules concerning division of the rights upon divorce. Generally speaking, the various legal rules
that have been developed reflect the Chinese predilection to favor control and
guidance from government over individual freedom of choice. Leases cannot be for more than 20 years. Lenders are strictly controlled as to how
much they can lend against the value of the land.
Although
the relatively new Basic Law of Contract proclaims that the parties are free to
contract as they please and that their bargains will be upheld, it remains to
be seen whether bargains will be upheld that create interests that are
inconsistent with the many regulations of the Bureau of Land Administration or
the Ministry of Construction. For
instance, one Chinese mortgage rule requires that all leases continue to exist
following a foreclosure of the landlord’s interest. In America, by contrast, there is extensive
bargaining among lender, landlord and tenant with respect to the possible
impact of foreclosure on the tenant’s rights, and a wide variety of outcomes
are possible. Another rule gives lessees
a “right of first refusal” to renew at the end of the lease term or to buy if
the landlord should sell the underlying ownership of the land. It is unclear whether this right can be “bought
out” in advance, although clearly many Chinese transactions attempt to do this.
The
Chinese legal system still does not
recognize formally many concepts that apparently are being developed
within the transaction system. There is
no clear “easement in gross,” for instance, so it is unclear under what rights
parties can extend pipelines or power lines.
Although hundreds of millions of Chinese have moved into condominium
residences in the last five years, there is no clearly developed condominium
law spelling out their rights and responsibilities toward one another.
There
is a proposal to include a section on property rights (“rights in rem”)
in the new Chinese Civil Code that is expected to be considered for adoption
this year. There have also been proposals
made by high Chinese leaders to amend the Constitution to provide better
protection for property interests, but the nature of these new changes remains
uncertain.
1.3. Other Property Rights and Expectations:
1.3.1. Homestead Rights:
There
are some rights to “homestead properties” that have been recognized as
traditional interests virtually since the establishment of the People’s
Republic. These properties exist both in
urban and rural areas. The nature and
basis of the rights has always been somewhat uncertain, as has been their
number. Homestead rights, however, have
never been viewed as granted land use rights, and it is unlikely that they have
much protection against appropriation by government. Some people with homestead rights have been
able to convert them to granted land use rights and now have a protectable
interest. Others lack the sophistication
or resources to carry out such conversions, and their interests remain
vulnerable.
1.3.2. Occupancy Expectations:
After
the Cultural Revolution, many people found themselves residing in or using
properties as to which there were no clear rights of occupancy. Records had either been destroyed or never
produced. As development has progressed,
many of these occupants have been forced to relocate. The granting of land use rights on property
that has been occupied in this way usually has required that the grantee pay
for the relocation of those on the land, whether or not they had any formal right
to be there. Twenty years ago, these
persons were given quite a lot of informal protection through the negotiation
of the granted land use rights.
In
recent years, the sale of granted land use rights has become an important
source of revenue for local and provincial governments, and there appears to be
less solicitude for “undocumented” occupants of property that is part of a
granted land use right. Although in
theory the government can require the grantee to pay the cost of relocation, I
have heard that the bargains over such relocation have led to less generous
settlements.
1.3.3. Household Responsibility System -
Agricultural Land
The
system of granted land use rights has been used primarily in urban areas and
for industrial and commercial development in the countryside. Agricultural property in the countryside has
been under the control of agricultural collectives who have reallocated the
property under their control to individual peasants under a system known as the
“household responsibility system.”
Peasants live and work on their allocated farm plots and have some
autonomy in the management of their agricultural enterprises. We have heard stories recently of the
wholesale breakdown of this system in the countryside as opportunities have
arisen to consolidate land for purposes of corporate farming or industrial or
commercial development. It appears that
the individual peasants may in many cases
be relinquishing their household responsibility ownership voluntarily
for these purposes, but we have heard many reports that they do thereafter
receive benefit from the reapplication of the property to other purposes that
one would have expected them to enjoy as members of the Collective.
This
problem may be a problem of failure to enforce legal rights and it may be a
problem of simple fraud and sharp dealing by leaders in these countryside
Collectives. Reports are, however, that
the phenomenon is widespread in rural China.
A
very recent new statute addressing some of these issues has been passed, and is
discussed by another panelist. It
remains to be seen whether the statute will be effective to slow down what
appears to be a widespread movement.
2.0. Problems with enforcement of legal rights.
2.1. The problem of diffusion of legal power:
It
is important to recognize that legal power in China is widely distributed. The popular U.S. image of the all powerful
monolithic central government is not an accurate picture of China in the area
of economic rights. It is true that
there is a tradition of overbearing government control in China, and
consequently when central government and local government interests coincide,
or at least do not conflict, it would appear that the Central Government has
the power to effect strong controls over the population.
But
in the area of division and management of economic resources such as land,
there often are conflicts between the Central Government and provincial and
local authorities. The Central
Government lacks the political and social strength to prevail in many of these
conflicts. Thus, even when the Central
Government proposes a system of legal rights and expectations that may be
sufficient to form a basis for a successful market system, it is up to the
Provincial and local governments to provide effective enforcement mechanisms to
insure that the system really works.
In
Guangzhou, Shanghai, Beijing, and other important commercial centers, there is
recognition that a transparent legal system is vital to attracting investment
capital and encouraging economic risk taking.
Consequently, the legal system tends to follow the dictates of the
Central Government rules, although extensive additional local control over real
estate practices is commonplace. Often
the local regulation in these areas, in fact, is benevolent, and assists in
promoting effective market transactions by “filling in the gaps” of national
rules.
This
happy story of cooperation, however, is not repeated in many other areas. Local, County and Provincial governments
control large sections of the taxing system and control the payrolls and other
benefits that support courts and other agencies that are nominally organs of
the Central Government. Consequently,
when conflicts arise between local government interests and the interest of
stability and predictability in the legal system, judges and administrators
find themselves often under intolerable pressure. We have heard many tales of foreclosure
proceedings delayed into exhaustion, of transfers of land use rights without
regard to government required plans and pursuant to special negotiations that
might be viewed as inconsistent with concepts of fair opportunity.
If
anything, the current frenzy of land development in China has increased the motive
and opportunity for local leaders to ignore the rules in the name of
expediency. Often this situation
provides a breeding ground for corruption, and even more often individual
property rights are frustrated by such activities. We saw similar abuses occurring during “boom
time” periods in the development of our
own country, and I suggest we should be neither surprised nor too dismayed that
such things are now happening in China.
Ultimately, as we have seen in the larger cities, a recognition is likely
to develop that orderly process and clear rules will lead to greater economic
prosperity. Egregious examples of
corruption are periodically identified and dealt with, although cynics might
argue that such activities are really ways of disposing of the most
difficult political enemies rather than
the most troublesome thieves.
2.1. Addressing the problems:
As
I have suggested, to a certain extent, the problems observed in China are “boom
time” problems that will disappear over time.
But certainly an important factor in these problems is the lack of
adequately trained lawyers and judges.
Often departures from the national system of property management and
destruction of property rights occur because no one in the local area really
understands what the legal rules are.
Although
there is a large number of Chinese judges, many of them lack formal law
training and, unlike in America, even those with formal law training lack much
experience in law practice. Further,
there are few lawyers in many areas capable of insuring that their clients’
interests are protected by law. The
concept of the rule of law has only lately arrived in many Chinese provinces,
and established lawyers have been successful by paying more attention to
cultivating friends rather than advocating legal principles.
There
is a need to educate lawyers in many areas of China as to the nationally
mandated rules and procedures involved in the creation, transfer and protection
of property rights. There is a similar
need to provide such education for judges.
Further, there is a need to encourage capable graduates of China’s law
schools (which have grown exponentially in recent years) to move into the
outlying areas of China and to avoid the existing concentration in the major
financial centers.
2.2. Special needs in the housing market:
In
a recent meeting with leaders in China’s housing industry, there was general
agreement on the need for several social or legal developments to occur to
facilitate the continued growth and prosperity of private property exchange in
China:
a. A national system of reliable credit analysis
and review.
b. Development of autonomous and responsible
owners associations in Chinese housing
complexes.
c. Development of an industry for the resale of
residential property (now most Chinese housing is still occupied by the
original owner.)
d. Development of real estate specialization
among lawyers, who now are poorly prepared to address real estate problems in
the residential marketplace.
e. Resolution of the many conflicting provisions
of Chinese real estate law and greater contractual autonomy in the commercial
marketplace.
f. Meaningful consumer protection in the housing
development, finance, and resale markets.
g. Clear rules regarding bankruptcy.
h. As discussed above - adherence to national
laws and enforcement of those laws by courts and administrators.
2.3. The special problem of corruption:
China
needs to continue to be vigilant in the suppression of corruption. In my years in China, public concern about
corruption has become the single greatest complaint from the Chinese citizens I
meet. Ask any Beijing taxi driver!!
Land
use rights are sold and regulated by local officials. As public land now passes into private hands,
there are enormous opportunities for profiteering on two fronts. First, Chinese officials who generate
revenues from the sale of the land have power to allocate those revenues. In many cases, these revenues may be used to
finance joint venture investments by which individuals make great profits
through the exploitation of these government funds. Although a 1998 law requires that proceeds
from the sale of arable land be reinvested in the development of more arable
land, there is widespread belief that this law is being ignored in favor of
diversion of monies into other enterprises of more direct interest to the
specific public officials who control the sale of land use rights.
A
second means of corrupt practice in the creation of land use rights, of course,
is in the identification and regulation of those who receive land use
rights. In some areas, concerns about
corrupt practices in the awarding of land use rights to favored persons at low
prices reached such a pitch that sale by auction was required. But almost as soon as the auction requirement
was enacted, exceptions to the rules crept in that preserved the options of
local officials in “special cases.”
In
some cases, the creation of a “political machine” may have the short run
benefit of insuring stability where law may not accomplish that result. For instance, there is little question that
most housing development is being carried out by favored developers who have
the inside track on obtaining land use rights for these purposes. But the fact that they are on the “A list”
may lead these developers to be extra cautious to insure that they actual
produce the housing that is called for and that no scandals result in terms of
shoddy housing or sharp practices that
may jeopardize their ability to continue in their favored position. Indeed, we hear remarkably few complaints
about consumer housing considering the size of the market.
Inconsistent
regulation of land use development also can be a problem. Since the power of forfeiture for failure to
develop is so draconian, it is likely that there is some extortion going on
where the possibility of forfeiture exists.
The Chinese likely would be wise to consider less drastic interim
measures to cope with problems of slow development in order to ease the
friction at this point in the system.
A
country that lacks a free press is
particularly vulnerable to corruption.
Perhaps China’s greatest challenge in the economic arena is to secure
the confidence of its population in the fairness and openness of its system of
economic regulation, and China’s concern that unrestricted freedom of the press
endangers stability in other areas makes the achievement of such confidence far
more difficult.
3.0. The significance of property rights and human
rights.
It
should be noted at the outset that the recognition of property rights in China
has occurred for economic reasons - to encourage individual responsibility for
economic decisions that will fuel an effective marketplace and an adequate
distribution of resources. China wants its
population to have a better physical standard of living, and believes that
market principles may achieve that result.
In short, it can be said that the Chinese value individual property
because this is in the best interests of the collective.
Although
these considerations also are present in our political system, the recognition
of property rights in America is more fundamental, and reflects a social and
philosophical balance that is not necessarily a part of Chinese political
philosophy. We tend to view our citizens
as deserving of individual liberty and autonomy, and the recognition of private
property is an important part of that personal autonomy. Consequently we view individual property
rights as a distinct objective, and may sacrifice the interests of the
collective in some circumstances in order to protect such rights.
In
evaluating the progress of individual property rights in China, we should
maintain our focus on why China is promoting these rights, and not expect more
from China than it is reasonable to expect.
On
the other hand, I believe that the development a greater degree of individual
autonomy that inevitably results from the protection of property rights will
lead, ultimately, to stronger individual rights in other areas of Chinese life
as well. Those who have something to
protect and preserve often seek a greater voice in government. Chinese government is not closed to the
voices of the people. It is not as
responsive to those voices as might be the case in a democracy, but neither is
the Chinese government a despotic and uncaring parasite. But at present many Chinese citizens are “apolitical.”
As citizens in China increasingly become aware that governmental policies will
have a direct result on their opportunity to keep what they have and obtain
what they want, they will demand a greater voice in government, and will demand
that government respect their autonomy.
A
significant problem in this development, of course, is the fact that the
Chinese government’s second great goal, concurrent with economic development,
is political stability. The development
of greater citizen participation in government threatens those with entrenched
power, and it is only a short step from perception of a challenge to ones power
to the conclusion that government stability is in danger. But the development of individual property
interests is so much a part of the economic system at present that it does seem
unlikely that Chinese officials will take significant steps to frustrate such
expectations. Accommodation of political
change, therefore, is possible and it is likely that the change will be in
favor of greater levels of individual autonomy.
Other
institutions in the society that serve to promote the market economy - such as
the development of trained lawyers and other social advocates, private trade
associations such as brokers groups and owners groups, and the free exchange of
information that necessarily flows through a market economy, will lead to
social expectation of greater power and gradual reform.
Consequently, U.S. policy in the area of Chinese real estate ought to be to recognize that a healthy system of exchange of private real estate interests is likely to lead ultimately to demand for and realization of a greater individual autonomy and citizen voice in government in China, both goals that are critical to the greater development of human rights.